Overview of New Economic Systems

By Eman M. Elshaikh
We’re used to credit cards now, but the very idea of credit, interest, and banking were pretty radical innovations in our economic history—and they led to the emergence of capitalism in Europe.

Cookie Policy

Our website uses cookies to understand content and feature usage to drive site improvements over time. To learn more, review our Terms of Use and Privacy Policy.

A painting of many men crowded in a courtyard. Many are wearing grand-looking clothing, such as tall hats and long overcoats.

Introduction

A character in Shakespeare’s play Hamlet once told his son: “Neither a borrower nor a lender be.” His words suggested that lending money was immoral, but if you look at the economic history of the world in Era 5 (when Hamlet was written), people didn’t really follow that advice. By Shakespeare’s time, lending money had become incredibly common! Loans were part of a broader pattern of economic change that completely reshaped global production and distribution. These changes formed new networks, created a middle class, and also contributed to the rise of nation-states and capitalism.

Innovations in finance

First, let’s define credit. A loan is an amount of money that a lender lends to a borrower. Credit is an agreement between a borrower and a lender that a loan will be repaid later. In many cases, the agreement includes interest, which is what the borrower must repay in addition to the value of the initial loan. There is evidence that humans were using credit and interest as early as 2000 BCE in Mesopotamia.

Square-shaped stone slab that has text carved into it.
Mesopotamian tablet from c. 1780 BCE with a contract for a loan of barley carved in cuneiform. By the Metropolitan Museum of Art, public domain.

So why did a Shakespearean character say it was so wrong 3,600 years later? Why was it not commonly used? First, charging interest was generally banned by the Christian Church and Islam, so other groups, who were often excluded from business opportunities and many professions, tended to be the only ones who did it. Many of these money-lenders were Jews, who faced increased discrimination for their work.

Fibonacci’s Liber Abaci

A page of a book covered in calligraphy. The page looks old and is yellowed slightly.
A page from the Liber Abaci. Public domain.

Besides the moral issues, Europeans just didn’t know how to use these technologies. Leonardo of Pisa, also known as Fibonacci (c. 1175-1250), wrote a book called Liber Abaci that changed all of that. Fibonacci traveled to India and the Middle East, where he learned about new mathematical concepts. His book introduced Europe to fractions and decimals as well as the Hindu-Arabic numeral system (1,2,3, etc.), which worked a lot better than Roman numerals. Without the Hindu-Arabic system, a phone number like 867-5309 would look like this: VIII VI VII - V III NULLA IX. Fibonacci’s book also contained important ideas that helped solve existing economic problems, like putting a price on products and calculating profits and interest rates.

The first modern banks

Fibonacci’s ideas helped business boom in Venice and Florence, Italy. These cities were part of vast trade networks, and where the first banks opened. Today banks are common, but a few hundred years ago the concept of an institution that manages money and loans was brand new.

Banks developed new ways to deal with money, such as the bill of exchange or promissory note. A buyer would give a seller a bill of exchange, which the seller would take to the bank in order to receive their money. Bills of exchange helped people give money to each other without exchanging cash, and they were safer to transport across long distances. If they sound familiar, it’s because they’re related to modern-day checks.

International currency exchange

For a while, the Mediterranean was a banking hotspot. But power eventually shifted from the Mediterranean to Northern Europe. Dutch, British and Swedish banks developed new financial technologies, like exchanging currencies. Currency exchange is when a type of money from one country is traded for money from another country. Trade got more efficient, because now you could move money without having to use coins or bills of exchange.

Bonds

Around this time, banks started to manage money on much larger scales, including dealing with government debt. Some countries even paid for wars with bonds, which were basically loans in which individuals lent money to the government through a bank. The government promised to pay back the loan plus interest at a later date.

Several men wearing long, wavy wigs sit and stand around a table in discussion
Sealing of the Bank of England Charter (1694), by Lady Jane Lindsay, 1905. Public domain.

Colonialism and the rise of joint-stock companies

These financial technologies revolutionized the way many nations dealt with trade, war, and establishing colonies. International trade could bring great profits, but it was expensive to send a fleet of ships across the ocean. Few individuals were willing to take the risk on their own.

Joint-stock companies helped solve this problem. Joint-stock companies were owned by several individuals who split business costs and shared the profits. Of course the business could still fail, but joint-stock companies made it so a few people could lose some money instead of one person losing everything. Soon, stock markets
emerged, making it easy to buy and sell shares in a company. For better or for worse, a much larger segment of the population were now traders.

Empires as businesses

Joint-stock companies had already been used in other places such as Song Dynasty China around 1000 CE. They were also around in a different form in the Muslim world. But in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, the joint- stock model really took off in Europe.

Colonizing projects were often paid for by joint-stock companies instead of governments. Join-stock companies like the British East India Company and Dutch East India Company managed overseas colonies in India on behalf of the British and Dutch governments. But these were companies, not governments, even though they sometimes acted like governments including waging war.

A painting depicts many large sailing ships on the sea, waving different flags. In the background is a port city.
A painting by the Flemish artist Andries van Eertvelt depicting ships returning from an early Dutch trading expedition to the East Indies in 1599, with the city of Amsterdam visible on the right. Public domain.

A global competition

European countries began to see other nations as competition, so they began promoting mercantilist policies. Mercantilism is a system for buying and selling goods where governments controlled that trade. The goal is to sell more than you buy to make your country wealthier and more self-sufficient.

At that time, European demand for foreign goods was growing. However, it was expensive to import those goods from other countries. Mercantilism increased interest in forming colonies for a couple of reasons. The colonies had all the materials needed to make the things people wanted to buy, and they were new places for Europeans to sell their goods. However, the people who lived in the colonies could not trade with other countries.

The rise of the middle class

Business was booming, at least for Europeans. In a world that used to be just a few rich people and a whole lot of poor people, middle classes began to emerge. This had a lot to do with the rise of the merchant class, which was able to make money through trade. This wealth made the middle classes more powerful, but they still wanted more political power. All this led to a new social and political environment during the seventeenth and early eighteenth centuries.

Capitalism and the free market

Around that time, a new economic system started to emerge: capitalism. Capitalism is a system in which a country’s businesses are controlled by private companies, not the government or workers. Eventually, some European governments allowed private companies to buy and sell without too much government involvement. Joint- stock companies and individuals began hiring wage laborers, who had to sell their labor in addition to using their own tools and farms. Capitalists made huge profits, but they did not have to share that profit with their workers.

Conclusion

The effects of these changes were huge. Credit grew in Era 5, while joint-stock companies directly contributed to the expansion of colonies. The other big reboot was production and distribution. Goods were being produced in the European colonies, but they were being sold in both Europe and the colonies. The flow of goods created new nations with distinct social classes. Europeans adopted capitalism, which would completely change production and distribution around the world.

Sources

Ashtor, Eliyahu. “Banking Instruments Between the Muslim East and the Christian West” 3 (1972). http://www.jeeh.it/articolo?urn=urn:abi:abi:RIV.JOU:1972;3.553&ev=1

Banaji, Jairus. “Islam, the Mediterranean and the Rise of Capitalism.” Historical Materialism 15, no. 1 (2007): 47–74. https://doi.org/10.1163/156920607X171591

Ferguson, Niall. The Ascent of Money : A Financial History of the World. New York: Penguin Press, 2008.

Goetzmann, William N. Money Changes Everything : How Finance Made Civilization Possible. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2016.

Goetzmann, William N., K. Geert Rouwenhorst –, Marc van de Mieroop –, Ulrike Malmendier –, Valerie Hansen, Ana Mata-Fink –, Richard von Glahn –, et al., eds. The Origins of Value : The Financial Innovations That Created Modern Capital Markets. Oxford ; New York: Oxford University Press, 2005.

Heck, Gene W. Charlemagne, Muhammad, and the Arab Roots of Capitalism. Studien Zur Geschichte Und Kultur Des Islamischen Orients (2004) ; Berlin ; New York: De Gruyter, 2006.

Labib, Subhi Y. “Capitalism in Medieval Islam.” The Journal of Economic History 29, no. 1 (1969): 79–96.

Lieber, Alfred E. “Eastern Business Practices and Medieval European Commerce.” The Economic History Review 21, no. 2 (1968): 230–43. https://doi.org/10.2307/2592433.

Quinn, Stephen F., and William Roberds. “The Evolution of the Check as a Means of Payment: A Historical Survey.” Economic Review, 2008. https://ideas.repec.org/a/fip/fedaer/y2008nv.93no.4.html.

Saeed, A, and O Salah. “Development of Sukuk: Pragmatic and Idealist Approaches to Sukuk Structures,” no. 1 (2013): 12.

Skeen, Bradley. “Trade and Exchange: The Islamic World.” In Encyclopedia of Society and Culture in the Medieval World, edited by Pam J. Crabtree, 1093–95. Facts on File Library of World History. New York: Facts On File, 2008.

Udovitch, Abraham L. Bankers without Banks : Commerce, Banking, and Society in the Islamic World of the Middle Ages. Princeton, N.J.: Program in Near Eastern Studies, Princeton University, 1981.

“What Is Capitalism? - Back to Basics - Finance & Development, June 2015.” Accessed July 30, 2019. https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2015/06/basics.htm

Eman M. Elshaikh

The author of this article is Eman M. Elshaikh. She is a writer, researcher, and teacher who has taught K-12 and undergraduates in the United States and in the Middle East and written for many different audiences. She teaches writing at the University of Chicago, where she also completed her master’s in social sciences and is currently pursuing her PhD. She was previously a World History Fellow at Khan Academy, where she worked closely with the College Board to develop curriculum for AP World History.

Image credits

Creative Commons This work is licensed under CC BY 4.0 except for the following:

Cover: The courtyard of the Beurs in Amsterdam, Emanuel de Witte, public domain. https://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/File:The_courtyard_of_the_Beurs_in_Amsterdam,_by_Emanuel_de_Witte.jpg

Mesopotamian tablet from c. 1780 BCE with a contract for a loan of barley carved in cuneiform. By the Metropolitan Museum of Art, Public domain. https://www.metmuseum.org/art/collection/search/321821

A page from the Liber Abaci. Public domain. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Liber_Abaci#/media/File:Liber_abbaci_magliab_f124r.jpg

Sealing of the Bank of England Charter (1694), by Lady Jane Lindsay, 1905. Public domain. https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Bank_of_England#/media/File:Bank_of_England_Charter_sealing_1694.jpg

A painting by the Flemish artist Andries van Eertvelt depicting ships returning from an early Dutch trading expedition to the East Indies in 1599, with the city of Amsterdam visible on the right. Public domain. https://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/File:The_Return_to_Amsterdam_of_the_Second_Expedition_to_the_East_Indies_on_19_July_1599.jpg#/media/File:The_Return_to_Amsterdam_of_the_Second_Expedition_to_the_East_Indies_on_19_July_1599.jpg


Newsela

Articles leveled by Newsela have been adjusted along several dimensions of text complexity including sentence structure, vocabulary and organization. The number followed by L indicates the Lexile measure of the article. For more information on Lexile measures and how they correspond to grade levels: www.lexile.com/educators/understanding-lexile-measures/

To learn more about Newsela, visit www.newsela.com/about.

The Lexile Framework for Reading

The Lexile® Framework for Reading evaluates reading ability and text complexity on the same developmental scale. Unlike other measurement systems, the Lexile Framework determines reading ability based on actual assessments, rather than generalized age or grade levels. Recognized as the standard for matching readers with texts, tens of millions of students worldwide receive a Lexile measure that helps them find targeted readings from the more than 100 million articles, books and websites that have been measured. Lexile measures connect learners of all ages with resources at the right level of challenge and monitors their progress toward state and national proficiency standards. More information about the Lexile® Framework can be found at www.Lexile.com.